TaxProf Blog

Editor: Paul L. Caron
Pepperdine University School of Law

A Member of the Law Professor Blogs Network

Tuesday, September 5, 2006

Davis: Another Constitutional Shot Across the Tax Bow

There is yet another earth-shattering constitutional tax case:  in Davis v. Department of Revenue, No. 2004-CA-001940-MR (Kent. Ct. App. 1/6/06), the Kentucky Court of Appeals held that the state's tax system violates the dormant commerce clause of the U.S. Constitution by exempting interest on Kentucky state & local bonds while taxing interest on out of state bonds. The opinion notes that Kentucky's system is used in a majority of states, and that the only court to consider the commerce clause issue (Ohio) upheld the constitutionality of the system. Last month, the Kentucky Supreme Court denied the state's motion for discretionary review.  Department of Revenue v. Davis, No. 2006-SC-105-D (8/17/06).

Below the fold, you will find commentary from four Tax Profs who take very different positions on the correctness of the Davis decision:

  • Richard Pomp (Connecticut)
  • Kirk Stark (UCLA)
  • Calvin Johnson (Texas)
  • Greg Germain (Syracuse)
  • Richard Pomp (Connecticut):

The case is clearly correct. The interesting question is why others have not challenged the issue by now. The answer seems to be fear of the remedy. The logical remedy would be to tax all interest from state bonds, which might by a phyrric victory. I understand that because of features of Kentucky law, that remedy was not available so all interest will be exempt.

  • Kirk Stark (UCLA):

Should states be allowed to exempt the interest on their own bonds while taxing the interest on bonds issued by other states? To the extent that a state’s exemption lowers the borrowing cost for its bond-issuing governments, another way of framing the question is to ask whether a state must subsidize the borrowing activities of other states and their political subdivisions. In other words, is Indiana constitutionally obligated to subsidize the borrowing costs of the Los Angeles Unified School District? According to the theory of the Kentucky case, the answer is “yes” because Article I, Section 8 of the U.S. Constitution says that “Congress shall have Power … to regulate Commerce … among the several States.” Since these eleven words really say nothing at all about the question presented, it should come as no surprise that the Ohio case came out the other way. It is tempting to view the U.S. Supreme Court as the ultimate arbiter of these sorts of conflicts, but if history is any guide an opinion from that court will only produce more uncertainty about what states can and cannot tax. The very fact that this seemingly basic legal issue remains unresolved is evidence of how muddled the Supreme Court’s “dormant commerce clause” jurisprudence really is. The Davis case is another example of the need for a fundamental rethinking of the way we make law in this area. Congress should exercise its power to regulate interstate commerce by establishing an alternative tribunal—an Interstate Commerce Court—to resolve these disputes as they arise.

  • Calvin Johnson (Texas):

Right on the merits. Articles of Confederation prohibited any state from imposing a tax or regulation on an out-of-state American that it was unwilling to impose on its own citizens. That norm was deep nomr of the Revolution to Constitution and it became the dormant commerce clause. The exemption does not work as a subsidy because too little of it is captured by the issuing authority and it survives politically because in-state investors get to keep so much of the benefit. A strong dormant clause is vital because every state legisture tries to subsidize state citizens to the exclusion and even harm to out of state voters because out of state citizens do not vote. Straight Buchanan like analysis says that states will always hurt out of state nonvoters if they can get away with it.

  • Greg Germain (Syracuse):

I think the Kentucky Court of Appeals in Davis erred in failing to fully and correctly consider whether the government is acting as a regulator or market participant in allowing an exclusion to local taxpayers for in-state municipal bond interest while not allowing an exclusion to local taxpayers for out-of-state municipal bond interest.

The market participant language has been used by the Court to distinguish between direct subsidies given by the government for local activities (at a cost to the local taxpayers), and cost-free regulation by the government that favors in-state commerce at the expense of out-of-state commerce. Nowak & Rotunda, Constitutional Law, 7th Edition, p. 332-33 (2004)). The Supreme Court has recognized, for example, that a city can constitutionally require city workers to live within municipal boundaries, even though this employment law discriminates against out-of-city workers. This is because the city, in providing municipal employment, is acting as a market participant and not a regulator. Providing state employment is a direct subsidy by the state because the state is paying the wages. See McCarthy v. Philadelphia Civil Service Commissioner, 424 U.S. 645 (1976) (although commerce clause not specifically considered, Court indicated that constitution would not prevent state from discriminating in favor of locals when hiring municipal employees).

In W. Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 512 U.S. 186 (1994), the Supreme Court considered whether a combined tax and subsidy would be invalid under the commerce clause. Massachusetts imposed a uniform tax on all milk suppliers (in-state and out of state) and then used the proceeds from the tax to provide a subsidy to in-state milk producers. The net effect was two fold: (1) the in-state producers were essentially refunded their share of the tax, and (2) the in-state producers received a net subsidy from the tax collected from out-of-state producers. Because only out-of-state producers were really paying the tax (since the local producers were receiving a refund of their tax through the subsidy), the Court held that the tax constituted a tariff that violated the negative Commerce Clause. The Court looked to the substance of the combined tax-subsidy rather than the form in reaching its ruling, because viewed independently neither the tax nor subsidy would violate the commerce clause. The Court said "Although the tax also applies to milk produced in Massachusetts, its effect on Massachusetts producers is entirely (indeed more than) offset by the subsidy provided exclusively to Massachusetts dairy farmers. Like an ordinary tariff, the tax is thus effectively imposed only on out-of-state products." Id. at 195.

The Court also responded to the state's argument that the combined tax/subsidy should be legal because each part treated separately would be legal. In rejecting this argument, the Court noted that "[a] pure subsidy funded out of general revenue ordinarily imposes no burden on interstate commerce, but merely assists local business. The pricing order in this case, however, is funded principally from taxes on the sale of milk produced in other States. By so funding the subsidy, respondent not only assists local farmers, but burdens interstate commerce. The pricing order thus violates the cardinal principle that a State may not 'benefit in-state economic interests by burdening out-of-state competitors.' Id. at 199 (citations omitted). Had there been no tax on out-of-state producers to fund the subsidy, so that the subsidy was funded by in-state taxpayers - the subsidy would have been lawful. In a footnote, the Court noted that while it had never formally held that subsidies were constitutional, it had noted in a number of cases that subsidies do not violate the negative Commerce Clause. Id. at 199 n. 15.

Kentucky is not funding its subsidy with revenues from out-of-state citizens. Kentucky does not tax out-of-state citizens who purchase out-of-state bonds. Only in-state residents who buy out-of-state bonds pay a tax. The subsidy is funded from taxes collected by in-state residents (presumably both those who bought out-of-state bonds and other taxpayers).

In addition, the Court of Appeals did not consider the inherently governmental nature of the underlying activity - municipal bond sales. The purpose of the negative Commerce Clause is to prevent state regulation that benefits local industry at the expense of out-of-state industry. However, Kentucky is subsidizing governmental bond sales - a proprietary state activity - not local industry. In encouraging its citizens to buy its bonds, Kentucky is acting as a market participant. The discriminatory effect is only on other states in carrying out their proprietary funding activities. The commerce clause was not designed to inhibit state proprietary activity, but rather state attempts to regulate commercial activity for local benefit. Therefore, the subsidy provided to in-state purchasers of in-state bonds in the form of an exclusion from income tax appears to be a lawful subsidy. The State of Kentucky is simply providing a subsidy in the form of an income tax exclusion for people who buy Kentucky bonds. Kentucky could do the same thing by offering a higher interest rate on its bonds than is being offered by other states, and allowing only in-state residents to buy its bonds. There is no commerce clause objection to a state providing state benefits only to its own citizens.

I therefore believe that the Kentucky Court of Appeals erred on two counts. First, it failed to distinguish the inherently governmental activity of issuing bonds from ordinary non-governmental commercial activity. Second, it failed to distinguish between a valid direct subsidy in the form of a tax exclusion paid for by local citizens from an invalid regulation that burdens out-of-state industry at no cost to local citizens.

http://taxprof.typepad.com/taxprof_blog/2006/09/davis_another_c.html

New Cases | Permalink

TrackBack URL for this entry:

http://www.typepad.com/services/trackback/6a00d8341c4eab53ef00d834aeb07353ef

Listed below are links to weblogs that reference Davis: Another Constitutional Shot Across the Tax Bow:

Comments

What am I missing here? The Commerce Clause restricts state's from unauthorized discrimination against interstate or foreign commerce. State and local government activity is not commerce. So why should the Commerce Clause restrict states from discriminating in favor of their own non-commercial governmental activity?

Posted by: JimW | Sep 6, 2006 9:17:47 AM